Select Page

Reciprocal Tariff Ignorance

President Trump continues to pursue his misguided tariff crusade believing that he is somehow protecting American industries and employment. His latest move, reciprocal tariffs (which he intends to begin April 2), is even worse. Trump has stated that he plans to impose tariffs based on “what they charge us, we charge them,” which is an economically stupid idea. Advocates of this policy like to argue that it’s based on fairness, but it certainly is anything but that.

From a practical standpoint, the United States trades with around 200 countries covering about 13,000 items. Is Trump really going to go head-to-head on this many goods? Just the onerous price adjustment and management of it all on a continuous basis will add to the bureaucratic nightmare that Trump says he wishes to avoid. 

Furthermore, if Trump cares about America first, he should forget the concept of reciprocal tax policy. Otherwise, by imposing tariffs based on what other countries charge us, he’s letting other nations set our rates. This would not be looking out for America’s best interest; it’s a game of tit-for-tat — with other nations leading it!

Likewise, Trump is completely tone-deaf on how reciprocal tariffs would impact the average consumer. With tariffs already raising the cost of imported goods, reciprocal tariffs can escalate markets into a trade war. Not only will this continue to drive up prices, but it can also disrupt international trade and global supply chains. With the price of goods artificially raised in such a retaliatory relationship, Americans and American businesses will be less able to get the goods they need at the lowest cost. 

While Trump sees reciprocal tariffs as a means to leverage negotiations with other countries, he’s not interested in encouraging fair-trade practices or diversifying trade relationships. He engaged in a type of political signaling that looks more like economic strong-arming, except that Trump doesn’t understand the long-term economic harm reciprocal tariffs create. Whatever short-term political gain Trump thinks he is creating for this country (or himself) will only burden American consumers with higher prices and economic instability in the long run.

An Elise Stefanik Misstep

Elise Stefanik has been one of the most important Congresswomen for the Republican party in recent years. Amazingly, she has turned a purple part of New York into  a red one, which is no easy feat. Stefanik is currently awaiting confirmation for her appointment to be the ambassador to the UN, which is a critical post and a great choice for our country.

 That is why I was quite dismayed to see a petition to encourage the impeachment of judges, sponsored by the Stefanik Campaign. The petition was encouraging impeachment of judges who had made what many, including myself, believed to be bad decisions.

This is an utterly terrible idea. Even if you don’t like the decision a judge makes, calling for impeachment is just not the way to deal with a bad decision. The decision should be appealed. What  made this action even worse was that there was neither an attempt to describe what was legally wrong about the decision, nor any description or indication of what any impeachable offense was. Even a judge entering a misguided nationwide injunction is certainly not grounds for impeachment. Such a decision should be reversed on appeal so that there are more appropriate guidelines to prevent additional misguided nationwide injunctions in the future. 

Impeachment is for bad actions, not bad decisions. Stefanik would be wise to disavow support for this egregious idea and she should persuade Trump to do the same.

Tariffs are Not Pro-Growth

How can protectionists like Trump and his allies not understand that tariffs are destructive? A tariff is basically a tax on imports. It is championed as a means to boost domestic production and government revenue, but this is far from economic reality. Tariffs clearly and consistently hurt the consumer and taxpayer by driving costs up to everybody in amounts far in excess of any short-term benefits.

Tariffs further add to inflation and put American companies at a disadvantage because foreign countries can (and do) retaliate by putting their own tariffs on our exports. This slows manufacturing growth (the cost of their inputs go up), increases prices, and makes the economy more sluggish. On the other hand, free trade creates better choices for consumers and more global opportunities for American companies, resulting in lower costs and an expanded job market.

Even media outlets like the NY Post and Fox News are still parroting the mantra that even though tariffs are bad, they could have long term benefits. These benefits are supposed to be because they will achieve an overall reduction of foreign tariffs against the US, which will allow US companies to make more profits. Though this sounds like it may be right, there has never been any evidence that this is the case (the most logical reason being that because the US economy is so much stronger than other economies, there may be some real economic rationale that tariffs should not be reciprocal).

To suggest a tariff is a pro-growth economic policy is utterly ridiculous. Tariffs don’t strengthen American manufacturers; they are cronyism of the highest order.  Protectionists are economically ignorant, and tariffs have proven yet again to be disastrous for our economy.

The Wisdom of Thomas Sowell

Back in 2010, Thomas Sowell penned a fantastic essay over at the Jewish World Review shortly before the mid-term elections that year. Sowell reminded us of the disastrous effects of government intervention into the economy during the Great Depression–-a situation that is arguably being paralleled again today. I wanted to share his wisdom as some food-for-thought for those who think the government get more involved in trying to fix the economy.

Brass Oldies: Part II

“Songs that are “golden oldies” have much less pleasant counterparts in politics– namely, ideas and policies that have failed disastrously in the past but still keep coming back to be advocated and imposed by government. Some people may think these ideas are as good as gold, but brass has often been mistaken for gold by people who don’t look closely enough.

One of these brass oldies is the idea that the government can and must reduce unemployment by “creating jobs.” Some people point to the history of the Great Depression of the 1930s, when unemployment peaked at 25 percent, as proof that the government cannot simply stand by and do nothing when so many millions of people are out of work.

If we are going to look back at history, we need to make sure the history we look at is accurate. First of all, unemployment never hit 25 percent until after– repeat, AFTER– the federal government intervened in the economy.

What was unemployment like when the federal government first intervened in the economy after the stock market crash of 1929? It was 6.3 percent when that first intervention took place in June 1930– down from a peak of 9 percent in December 1929, two months after the stock market crash.

Unemployment never hit double digits in any of the 12 months following the stock market crash of 1929. But it hit double digits within 6 months after government intervention– and unemployment stayed in double digits for the entire remainder of the decade, as the government went in for one intervention after another.

The first federal intervention in June 1930 was the passage of the Smoot-Hawley tariffs by a Democratic Congress, a bill signed into law by Republican President Herbert Hoover. It was “bipartisan”– but bipartisan nonsense is still nonsense and a bipartisan disaster is still a disaster.

The idea behind these higher tariffs was that reducing our imports of foreign goods would create more jobs for American workers. It sounds plausible, but more than a thousand economists took out newspaper ads, warning that these tariffs would be counterproductive.

That was because other countries would retaliate with their own import restrictions, reducing American exports, thereby destroying American jobs. That is exactly what happened. But there are still people today who repeat the brass oldie that restricting imports will save American jobs.

You can always save particular jobs in a particular industry with import restrictions. But you lose other jobs in other industries, not only because other countries retaliate, but also because of the economic repercussions at home.

You can save jobs in the American sugar industry by restricting imports of foreign sugar. But that results in higher sugar prices within the United States, leading to higher costs for American candy producers, as well as American producers of other products containing sugar. That leads to higher prices for those products, which in turn means lower sales at home and abroad– and therefore fewer jobs in those industries.

A study concluded that there were three times as many jobs lost in the confection industry as were saved in the sugar industry. Restrictions on steel imports likewise led to an estimated 5,000 jobs being saved in the steel industry– and 26,000 jobs being lost in industries producing products made of steel.

Similarly, the whole idea of the government itself “creating jobs” is based on regarding the particular jobs created by government as being a net increase in the total number of jobs in the economy. But, since the government does not create wealth to pay for these jobs, but only transfers wealth from the private sector, that leaves less wealth for private employers to create jobs.

Songs that are golden oldies bring enjoyment when they return. But brass oldies in politics just repeat the original disasters.

A statistical analysis by economists, published in 2004, concluded that federal interventions had prolonged the Great Depression of the 1930s by several years. How long will future research show that current government interventions prolonged the economic crisis we are living through now?”

BBC’s Distorted Coverage: A Shameful Betrayal of Journalism and Truth

The BBC is one of the largest media organizations in the world, reaching hundreds of millions of readers per week. However, their articles covering the Israel-Hamas war have contained blatant violations of honest reporting as well as their own editorial guidelines. These are not isolated incidents; abuses have occurred over 1,500 times in their coverage of the Israel-Hamas war.

Research conducted by lawyer Trevor Asserson found substantial evidence of bias against Israel, including a tendency to associate Israel with genocide – despite the fact that Israel has never by word or deed, expressed any intention of eliminating Palestine or its people, and Hamas has expressed openly and consistently their desire to eliminate Israel and its Jews from the face of the Earth (genocide). The report also raises concerns about BBC Arabic’s coverage, noting instances where journalists reportedly showed support for Hamas.

In response, the BBC questioned the report’s methodology, particularly the use of AI for analysis. However, dismissing the report based on AI is disingenuous, since they don’t contest the validity of the findings. AI is a powerful tool for analyzing large volumes of text efficiently and objectively, enabling researchers to identify patterns and biases that might be missed by human reviewers. Its application does not undermine the report; instead, it enhances the analysis by providing a comprehensive view of the content. Additionally, the research was conducted by a team of legal experts and data scientists, meaning that AI analysis complemented, rather than replaced, human oversight and contextual understanding.

The BBC’s insistence on questioning the methodology is clearly just a smokescreen since they don’t even deny the bias and shoddiness of their reporting. Historical evidence shows that media outlets can exhibit bias, and previous studies validate the effectiveness of AI tools in uncovering such biases across various contexts. As a public service broadcaster, the BBC has a responsibility to uphold transparency and accountability. Given these findings, there are serious questions about its suitability for continued public funding.

Alexa the Influencer

People laughed at Amazon’s Alexa when it was discovered that asking a question regarding Kamala Harris would give you a good positive answer, but asking about Trump would give you a negative answer. We were told that this was corrected, and in fact, if such questions are asked now, Alexa will simply reply that she cannot respond to questions of a political nature.

But what constitutes a political question? I decided to find out. So I asked Alexa to tell me about Kamala Harris‘s tax policy. She responded that she found the following information from a website. Alexa then proceeded for at least 2 1/2 minutes extolling the wonderful virtues of Kamala Harris‘s tax policy —  except that it was blatantly partisan garbage and factually incorrect. For example, Alexa described how Harris strongly believed that lower capital gains rates are needed for economic growth. Therefore, she is proposing to reduce the capital gains rate from Biden’s proposal of nearly 50% to a mere 28%. But this is an utter lie! The Capital gains rate is currently 20% and has been since the Obama Administration. Harris’s proposal actually raises the capital gains rate to 33%, despite the fact that she knows it will hurt economic growth. 

I then asked Alexa to tell me about Donald Trump’s tax policy. Alexa simply replied, “sorry I don’t have any information about that.” Nevermind the fact that he was a US President for four years and has been a candidate for President for two election cycles!

It is clear that Amazon is disingenuously building partisan politics into its Alexa app, despite its protestations that it is not doing so.

Capital Gains and Fairness

Kamala Harris has just proposed a reduction in the capital gains rate increase that had been included in the Biden-Harris tax proposal. The reduction was from Biden’s 43.4% proposed rate to a 33% rate, both of which are ludicrous from an economic perspective. (Note that even the 33% rate is a 40% increase from the present rate of 23.8%!). A capital gain rate that high would severely inhibit people from selling assets at a gain. This would actually reduce the amount of revenue to be raised from this tax. Furthermore,  the effect of higher taxes slows the economy because those paying the higher capital gains have less money to invest.  

Back in 2008 when Obama was debating Hillary Clinton on national TV, Obama discussed with the moderator how raising the capital gains rate would likely reduce federal revenue collections, but he insisted it was good policy anyway — because it was a policy of “fairness”. Yes, knowledgeable people laughed at this, since fairness would actually have required a lower tax rate, and decreasing revenue by increasing taxes couldn’t be more stupid. And as Economics 101 would dictate, we actually experienced a sluggish economy after Obama raised the capital gains rate from 15%-20% (and then tacked on the 3.8% Net Investment Income Tax). 

I wouldn’t expect Kamala Harris, who is basically clueless on matters of taxes and economics, to have been aware of this. But one would think that her advisers would be. 

It should also be noted that the capital gains rate, even at 33%% understates the actual tax burden. That’s because capital gains taxes on individuals is actually a second tax, this income having already been taxed at the corporate level. The effective tax rate is therefore in excess of 40%, and this doesn’t even include state taxes. The astoundingly negative effect of this tax increase on economic wealth can’t be overestimated.

The only saving grace is that this proposal is so economically counterproductive and stupid that it’s not likely to get any traction in Congress; Biden has been trying unsuccessfully to raise capital gains for years. It looks like we have another candidate who puts forth an initiative that she knows has very little chance of realization, but chooses to do so anyway so she can characterize the Republicans as protecting the wealthy while she can claim to protect the middle class. 

Greed and Power: The Union Monopoly That’s Crippling American Ports

The International Longshore and Warehouse Union (ILWU) and the International Longshoremen’s Association (ILA) have amassed ridiculous levels of control over U.S. ports, leveraging their historical influence, and union monopoly power to dominate port operations nationwide. 

One of the most glaring issues with the ILWU and ILA’s monopolistic grip on U.S. ports is the staggering compensation packages their members receive, which are wildly disproportionate to the work performed. Longshore workers, particularly on the West Coast, often earn six-figure salaries, with some senior members making well over $200,000 annually, along with massive benefit and pension plans. This level of compensation, secured through the unions’ ability to shut down entire ports during negotiations, places a significant financial burden on port operations, driving up costs for businesses and consumers alike. The inflated pay and benefits, which far exceed those of comparable jobs in other sectors, are a direct result of the unions’ monopolistic control, creating an unsustainable system that prioritizes union interests over economic efficiency.

Another significant and damaging way the ILWU and ILA maintain their grip on U.S. ports is through their fierce opposition to automation. Despite the clear benefits of increased efficiency, lower costs, and improved global competitiveness, these unions staunchly oppose automation, because it weakens their power (Wikipedia) (APM Research Lab). As a result, U.S. ports are significantly behind their global counterparts in adopting advanced technologies, leading to massive disruptions that affect the entire economy. The unions’ resistance to modernization highlights a deeper issue: when union monopolistic power is left unchecked, it can bring progress grinding to a halt and hold entire industries back from necessary evolution.

If the U.S. wants to maintain its position as a global economic leader, it must address the stranglehold that the ILWU and ILA have on our ports. This is about ensuring that our ports can operate efficiently, compete on a global scale, and keep costs down for American consumers and businesses. We need immediate action to break the union monopoly, modernize port operations, and embrace automation. Policymakers must step in to introduce reforms that will bring balance to labor negotiations, promote technological advancement, and prevent unions from holding the entire economy hostage. America’s place in the global economy depends on it.